mohan mba imsr

download mohan mba imsr

of 16

Transcript of mohan mba imsr

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    1/16

    Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Do market characteristics impact the relationshipbetween retailer characteristics and online prices?

    Rajkumar Venkatesan a,, Kumar Mehta b,1, Ravi Bapna c,2

    a 100 Darden Blvd., Darden Graduate School of Business, Charlottesville, VA 22903, United Statesb Management Information Systems, 4400 University Drive, MSN 5F4, School of Management,

    George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030, United Statesc Information Systems, Indian School of Business, Gachibowli, Hyderabad, 500 03 2, India

    Received in revised form 30 April 2006; accepted 30 April 2006

    Abstract

    We propose that market characteristics interact with retailer characteristics to determine online prices. The retailer characteristics examined

    includeservice quality of a retailer, channels of transaction provided by a retailer and the size of a retailer. The market characteristics capture

    the level and nature of competition, and the price level of a product. We utilize a Hierarchical Linear Model (HLM) framework for capturing

    and testing the proposed interactions. The better fit between the model and the online market structure is reflected by a twenty-five percent

    increase in explainable price dispersion over results from comparable studies. Our study demonstrates that while retailer characteristics do

    impact online prices, this influence is significantly enhanced or diminished by the accompanying market characteristics.

    2007 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Internet markets; Retailer pricing strategy; Retailer service quality; Competition

    Introduction

    Industry surveys show that online firms have transitioned

    from the initial phase of investment and brand-building to

    the profit maximization phase. The published profitability

    and sales reports from 2001 to 20033 indicate that Internet-

    based retailingis now a firmly established andan increasingly

    profitable market. In light of this maturation, it is imperative

    to ask whether the extant understanding of retailer pricing

    strategies comprehensively explains the online retailerspric-

    ing behavior. Shankar and Bolton (2004) have suggested

    that descriptive research on the determinants of retailer

    Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 434 924 6916; fax: +1 434 243 7676.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (R. Venkatesan),

    [email protected] (K. Mehta), ravi [email protected] (R. Bapna).1 Tel.: +1 703 993 9412; fax: +1 703 993 1809.2 Tel.: +1 860 486 8398; fax: +1 860 486 4839.3 eMarketer (2004) indicates 79 percent online retailers were profitable in

    2003. Further, a Mullaney (2003) indicates that 40 percent of the publicly

    traded Internet companies reported profits in 2002, with the key areas being

    online retailing and finance.

    pricing strategies aids managers in profiling their pricing

    practices and predicting competitors behavior. However, it

    is important to note that the Internet as a retailing channel

    is significantly different from the traditional marketplace.

    In contrast to the traditional channels, Internet is character-

    ized by vastly increased availability of information regarding

    product attributes, prices and retailer service quality metrics.

    A key challenge has been to obtain an understanding of the

    retailers continued ability to price differentiate in the face of

    lowered search costs in Internet markets. The main findings

    to date have been that(a) price dispersion in Internet mar-

    kets is persistent with time, (b) in some, but not all, instancesretailer service quality explainssome of thevariancein online

    prices, and (c) the transaction channels provided by a retailer

    and level of competition matter (see Pan et al. 2004 for a

    detailed review).

    Economic theories of consumer demand and retailer pric-

    ing suggest that product prices are a function of boththe

    characteristics of the retailers and the competition (Pakes

    2003; Betancourt and Gautschi 1993). Studies of pricing by

    grocery retailers in offline markets have found that retail-

    0022-4359/$ see front matter 2007 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2006.04.002

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_4/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2006.04.002http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_4/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2006.04.002mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    2/16

    310 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    ers customize their prices at the brand store level. They

    do so based on their intimate knowledge about their cus-

    tomers, product categories, store characteristics, and most

    importantly in response to market competition (Shankar

    and Bolton 2004). Empirical evidence also indicates that

    when setting prices the retailers consider multiple objec-

    tives such asreaction to competitor actions, maximizingstore brand share, and manufacturer incentives (Chintagunta

    2002). These observations from offline markets establish

    that retailers pricing decisions not only reflect their inter-

    nal resources and objectives, but also point to the fact that

    the retailers pay close attention to characteristics of the mar-

    ket in which they operate. We are motivated to investigate

    existence of a similar effect in online markets where these

    characteristics are easily observable by the retailers.

    A distinct feature of this study is that we explicitly incor-

    porate interactions between retailer and market level factors.We believe that by examining the moderating influence of

    market level factors, we can provide a more comprehensive

    picture of the relationship between prices and retailer char-

    Table 1

    Comparing proposed framework with existing studies

    Representative research Model includes characteristics of Major findings

    Shoppers Product Retailer Competition Competition and

    retailer Interaction

    Analytical models

    Lal and Sarvary (1999) Ya Y N N N Price sensitivity of online shoppers decreases when (1)

    there is a large pool of online shoppers, (2) nondigitalproduct attributes are important, (3) consumers have a

    favorable loyalty to the brand they currently own, and

    (4) the fixed cost of a shopping trip is higher than the

    cost of visiting an additional store.

    Chen and Hitt (2003) Y N Y N N Better known retailer has higher price on average than a

    lesser known retailer, but lower price on some products

    and/or some of the time resulting in price dispersion.

    Smith (2001) Y N Y N N Focus of consumer search on few well known retailers

    leads to interdependence among these and also higher

    prices. Lesser known retailers however adopt random

    pricing strategy in equilibrium.

    Empirical models

    Tang and Xing (2001) N H Y N N Traditional retailers charge the highest prices, followed

    by brick-and-click retailers, and pure-play retailers havethe lowest prices.

    Ancarani and Shankar

    (2004)

    N H Y N N With regard to posted prices, traditional retailers charge

    the highest prices, followed by multichannel retailers

    and pure play retailers. However, when shipping costs

    are included, multichannel retailers charge the highest,

    followed by pure-play retailers and traditional retailers.

    Baye and Morgan

    (2001)

    N Y N Y N Price dispersion is persistent with time. However,

    product life cycle leads to changes in number of

    competing firms and the range of price dispersion.

    Baye and Morgan

    (2003)

    N Y Y Y N Use certified versus noncertified merchants as a

    measure of good and poor service quality. Certified

    merchant enjoys a premium but vanishes with increased

    number of certified competing firms.

    Carlton and Chevalier

    (2001)

    N H Y Y N Manufacturers charge higher prices on their websites

    and limit availability to avoid some retailers from freeriding on the sales efforts of other retailers.

    Clay et al. (2001, 2002) N H N Y N Price dispersion is persistent with time, and decreases

    with increase in competition

    Baylis and Perloff

    (2002)

    N H Y N N Observed online price dispersion is not due to service

    differentiation.

    Pan et al. (2002, 2003b) N H Y Y N Significant portion of price dispersion is due to

    nonretailer characteristics. Increase in level of

    competition reduces prices charged by retailers at a

    diminishing rate. Influence of service quality is not

    consistent across product categories.

    Present study N H Y Y Y Do market characteristics interact with retailer

    characteristics to determine price levels?

    a Y: yes, N: no, H: homogenous products.

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    3/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 311

    acteristics. Especially since existing empirical evidence from

    analyses of online prices indicate only a weak influence of

    service qualityan important asset of retailers (Zeithaml et

    al. 2002). Considering the persistent online price dispersion,

    coupled with firms choice of strategic and tactical decisions

    based on the competitive forces that exist in their markets

    (Porter 2001), we examine whether this supposed anomalycan be explained by considering the interaction between the

    retailer and market characteristics.

    Research question

    The main objective of our paper is to study online retail-

    ers pricing strategies in a single framework that accounts for

    the influence of(a) retailer characteristics - service qual-

    ity and channels of transaction, (b) market characteristics -

    level and nature of competition, and the price of a product,

    and (c) interactions among these factors. Table 1 provides a

    comparison of our study with relevant literature. It is evident

    that the interaction between retailer and market characteris-tics and its effect on online prices has never been explicitly

    examined. This is the main focus of our study.

    In remainder of the paper we use retailer in reference

    to retailers with a web presence. They can be multichannel

    retailers, that is they mayhave a physical presence and/or also

    use a catalog channel. Our hypotheses and analyses focus on

    the online pricing strategies of these retailers.

    Expected contributions

    Our study intends to make two primary contributions.

    First, we develop an integrated framework for studying theinteractions between market and retailer characteristics. For

    retailers selling nondifferentiable products, market competi-

    tion can vary widely across products and product categories.

    The differences in competitive forces make it feasible for the

    retailer to make a strategicchoice (level of service quality, and

    transaction channels) across all products, and vary the tacti-

    cal decision (price level) in each product-market depending

    on what competitive forces exist. Pricing is thus determined

    by the interaction between the retailers strategic choices and

    the market forces. Substantively, study of the interaction also

    provides a better understanding of the competitive effects of

    service quality, a relevant but sparsely researched issue in

    marketing.

    Second, we highlight the fact that the determinants of

    retailer pricing decisions exist at two different levels of

    abstraction. Retailer characteristics such as service qual-

    ity and transaction channels vary across individual retailers.

    Market characteristicssuch as level and natureof competition

    vary across product-markets and are common to all retail-

    ers selling the particular product. Traditional linear models

    cannot accommodate simultaneous inclusion of the retailer

    and market characteristics and the interactions between them.

    We utilize a Hierarchical Linear Modeling (HLM) frame-

    work which explicitly incorporatesthe main effects of retailer

    and market level characteristics at different levels, and also

    accounts for the interactions between them (Raudenbush and

    Bryk 2002). This allows us to test not only whether, but also

    when and how in the context of various market forces, do ser-

    vice quality and channels of transaction influence a retailers

    online pricing decisions.

    We first present the conceptual model for our analysesand integrate the relevant literature to formulate five testable

    hypotheses. We then describe our data collection from het-

    erogeneous sources reflecting information widely available

    to the consumers and retailers alike and explain operational-

    ization of our constructs. Subsequently, we present the HLM

    framework which incorporates the factors at different levels

    of abstraction, and follow it up with discussion of the results

    from the analyses. We derive the managerial implications

    from our results, and conclude with a discussion on potential

    directions for future research.

    Conceptual model and hypotheses

    Main effects: influence of Internet retailer factors

    Service quality

    Varian (2000) predicted that over time two classes of retail-

    ers will emerge-low service/low price and high service/high

    price. A study of the online retail market by Pan et al. (2002)

    finds that service quality does explain a retailers ability to

    pricedifferentiate, albeit verylittle. In contrast, the theoretical

    expectations indicate service quality as an important factor

    in consumers choice of a retailer (Wolfinbarger and Gilly

    2003). Betancourt and Gautschi (1993) suggest that retail-ers provide services in order to reduce the customers total

    cost of consumption and that these services play an impor-

    tant role in customers selection of a retailer. They present an

    analytical model which shows that between two retailers sell-

    ing the same product, a consumer would be willing to pay a

    higher price for the higher service quality retailer, but only as

    long as the consumers valuation of the difference in service

    quality is more than the difference in prices between the two

    retailers. Based on theoretical expectations we hypothesize

    that:

    H1. The higher the service quality of a retailer the higher

    the prices charged.

    Channels of transactions

    Empirical evidence from several years of data indicates

    that multichannel retailers have higher price levels than pure-

    play (click only) retailers and brick-only retailers (Ancarani

    and Shankar 2004; Pan et al. 2003a; Ratchford et al. 2003).

    Due to their wide geographic presence, National Brick-and-

    Click retailers can provide customers value added services

    such as the ability to order products online and pick up

    (or in some cases return) the products in an offline store.

    Such services save time and provide added ease of use to

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    4/16

    312 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    consumers. These facilities, which we term as fulfillment

    and post-fulfillment facilities, lead to greater consumer trust

    thereby reducing the price sensitivity of consumers. On the

    other hand, the single distribution channel for a pure play

    (Internet or click only) retailer, lowers the inventory costs

    and can be potentially leveraged to price differentiate by cost

    leadership. Consistent with prior studies, we expect NationalBrick-and-Click retailers to price higher because of better

    brand recognition, greater trust, and provision of better ful-

    fillment and post-fulfillment facilities. Therefore,

    H2a. National Brick-and-Click retailers charge higher

    prices than pure-play retailers.

    Local Brick-and-Click retailers can provide better fulfill-

    ment and post-fulfillment facilities albeit in a local area and

    thus have the potential to charge higher prices relative to

    pure play retailers. Since they are expected to have lower

    brand recognition than National Brick-and-Click retailers,

    we expect their price levels to be lower than those of retail-ers with national presence. Local Brick-and-Click retailers

    aim to utilize their online presence to extend their geo-

    graphic reach beyond that of the traditional store. This would

    attract additional consumers without incurring significant

    additional costs. Based on valid expectations for both higher

    and lower prices, we do not specify any directional hypothe-

    ses related to the pricing strategy of Local Brick-and-Click

    retailers.

    Online retailers that provide direct mail catalogs bene-

    fit from lower costs because direct mail catalog companies

    need little modification to include online ordering capabili-

    ties into their existing business models (Doolin et al. 2003).This addition of online ordering improves the convenience

    they provide to customer and can help the direct mail catalog

    retailer to differentiate and charge higher prices. Similarly,

    pure play retailers are adding direct mail catalogs to their

    channel portfolio because(a) they can leverage existing

    infrastructure (distribution centers, customer service and tele-

    phone ordering) to support their direct mail catalog channel

    (Quick 2000), and (b) online retail managers believe that

    direct mail catalogs enables them to build brand recognition

    and increase trust among consumers (Quick 2000), thereby

    leading to higher prices. Hence, we hypothesize that:

    H2b. Online retailers that provide direct mail catalogs

    charge higher prices than pure-play retailers.

    Moderating effects

    The influence of retailer characteristics (service quality

    and channels of transaction) on online prices is expected

    to be moderated by market characteristics such aslevel

    of competition, nature of competition. The main effects of

    retailer characteristics explain how, within a product market,

    the prices vary across retailers. The moderating effects of

    market characteristics capture the differences in the influence

    of the retailer characteristics on online prices across product

    markets.

    Interaction of level of competition and service quality

    Cohen (2000a) presents the concept of Distortion in Infor-

    mation Function (DIF-ness) to measure consumers tendency

    to use heuristics when faced with large amount of informa-tion. DIF-ness suggests that till a certain threshold consumers

    scan the increasing number of choices and make a choice

    that maximizes their utility. Beyond this threshold, increase

    in alternatives can lead the consumers to use heuristics based

    on brand name and service quality, to make their selection.

    Research in signaling theory suggests that consumers often

    use price as a proxy for quality of product and/or retailer

    (Kirmani and Rao 2000).

    Considering these two aspects, we expect that when faced

    with small number of competitors in a product-market, retail-

    ers with high service quality can easily differentiate their

    services and charge a higher price. Increase in the number

    of competitors (DIF-ness) would initially force the retail-ers (especially higher service quality retailers) to lower their

    prices in order to avoid losing consumers to the competitors.

    When the number of competitors exceeds a certain threshold,

    both DIF-ness and signaling theory suggest that the con-

    sumers use of heuristics would counteract the downward

    pressure on prices created by increased competition. Thus,

    we propose that the number of competitors in a market would

    diminish the positive influence of service quality on prices;

    and the moderating influence of the number of competitors

    would be nonlinear in nature. With increase in competition

    high service quality retailers would charge higher prices than

    low service quality retailers. However, the difference in theprices of high and low service quality retailers is expected to

    reduce at a diminishing rate. We expect the level of competi-

    tion to capture the differences in the extent to which service

    quality influences the prices charged by retailers across prod-

    uct markets. We hypothesize that:

    H3. The positive influence of service quality on prices

    charged by a retailer is diminished, albeit at a decreasing

    rate, as the number of competitors increase.

    Interaction of price level and service quality

    The price of a given product implicitly denotes the per-

    ceived risk and is an important determinant of consumers

    involvement in a product (Cohen and Areni 1991). Accord-

    ing to Cohen (2000b), the consumers selection is based on

    risk averseness particularly when the price of a product is

    high. This would lead them to prefer retailers with high ser-

    vice quality, who benefit from the consumers risk averseness

    (or willingness to pay higher for service quality) by charging

    higher prices. The empirical evidence does indicate increase

    in price dispersion with increase in average price of the prod-

    uct (Pratt et al. 1979). This increase in dispersion could stem

    from theconsumers willingness to payhigher pricesto retail-

    ers who are able to reduce the perceived risk by inducing trust

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    5/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 313

    (Ba and Pavlou 2002). In product-markets at higher price

    levels, retailers who are able to foster trust by way of better

    service quality are afforded scope for pricedifferentiation and

    would charge relatively higher. Though for all products, the

    retailers with high service quality will charge higher prices

    than retailers with low service quality; their price premium

    would increase with the price of a product (Betancourt andGautschi 1993). We expect the price level of a product to

    reflect the differences in the influence of service quality on

    prices charged by retailers across different product markets,

    and propose:

    H4. The positive influence of service quality on prices

    charged by retailers is enhanced further as the price level

    of the product increases.

    Interaction of nature of competition and retailer

    characteristics

    A differentiation strategy can be successful if(1) the

    benefits provided by the differentiation are valued by the

    consumer, and (2) the differentiation is unique or not eas-

    ily replicated by the competitors (Barney 1991). In a market

    for nondifferentiable products, a retailer canoffer higher con-

    sumer benefits by providing high service quality. The ability

    to chargea price premium forthe higherservice quality would

    then depend on competition from retailers who provide sim-

    ilar or higher levels of service to consumers (Betancourt and

    Gautschi 1993). We define one aspect of the nature of compe-

    tition in a particular product market as the variation in service

    quality of the retailers selling that product.

    As mentioned earlier, in general (for all products) the high

    service quality retailers are expected to charge higher pricesthan the low service quality retailers. However, the differ-

    ence in the prices is expected to be higher in markets with

    a larger variation in service quality among retailers selling a

    product (where possessing high service quality is a unique

    asset) compared to markets with lower variation in service

    quality. We expect the variation in service quality to capture

    the extent of difference in the influence of service quality

    on prices charged by retailers across product markets. We

    hypothesize that:

    H5a. The positive influence of service quality on prices

    charged by retailers is further enhanced when there is a high

    variation in service quality among the retailers selling the

    product.

    We use number of National Brick-n-Click retailers as a

    proportion of total number retailers selling a particular prod-

    uct to capture a second aspect of nature of competition. 4

    4 Our hypotheses regarding the moderating influence of market charac-

    teristics are drawn on the basis that online retailers use the easily available

    competitive information to formulate their pricing strategies. We do not

    characterize competition in terms of the proportion of local brick and click

    retailers and retailers with catalog because information on whether an online

    Fig. 1. Joint influence of retailer and market characteristics.

    National Brick-n-Click retailers have a higher trust with

    consumers, and provide unique channel alternatives for ful-

    fillment and post-fulfillment processes, and thus can be

    expected to charge higher prices. However, this ability of

    a national retailer to price higher is dependent on the compe-

    tition from other National Brick-n-Click retailers. Increase

    in the number of National Brick-n-Click retailers selling a

    product would result in reduced ability to differentiate from

    each other in terms of multichannel benefits and result in

    diminishing their price premiums. We hypothesize that:

    H5b. The premium charged by a National Brick-n-Click

    retailer is diminished with an increase in the proportion of

    National Brick-n-Click retailers that sell a product.

    Data collection

    The criteria used for identifying data to collect was: (a)

    product categories that include nondifferentiable products to

    avoid price variation because of product differentiation, (b)

    availability of at least 20 products in each of the categories to

    indicate substantial penetration product in the online retail

    market, and (c) availability of a minimum of seven price

    quotes for each of the selected products to ensure a base level

    of competitive intensity. Using these criteria, eight product

    categories were selected-Books, Camcorders, DVDs, DVD

    players, PDAs, Printers, Scanners and Video Games. Table 2provides the summary information of the data collected for

    operationalizing the constructs presented earlier in Fig. 1.

    For each retailer we collected data for the service qual-

    ity ratings and the competitive intensity from Bizrate.com

    (similar to Pan et al. 2003b). The data for size of the retailer

    was obtained from Alexa.com which provides rank of the

    retailer is a localbrickand clickretailer orif a retailer hasalsohas a catalog is

    noteasilyevidentonline. However,we would expect consumers andNational

    Brick-and-Clickretailers to be aware of theidentityof other National Brick-

    and-Click retailers through the competitive intelligence surveys that are

    usually undertaken in firms of this size.

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    6/16

    314 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Table 2

    Constructs operationalized from multiple sources

    Construct Data collected Source Related research using similar measures

    Price Posted price for a product. Used to calculate

    the price index.

    Bizrate.com Pan et al. (2002), Clay et al. (2002)

    Service quality Survey ratings obtained by Bizrate from

    online consumers over ten items on a

    10-point scale (1 = Poor, 10 = Outstanding

    Bizrate.com Pan et al. (2002)

    Transactional channels Dummy coded variables for characterizing

    the channels through which the retailer

    offers the products. The channels are first

    classified as one of the following: pure play

    (online only), national chain with online

    presence, and local store(s) with online

    presence. In addition, we also distinguish

    retailers that offer mail-order catalog.

    Inspection of Retailer

    Websites

    Tang and Xing (2002)

    Size Rank of retailers based on number of unique

    visitors to the online.

    Alexa.com Pan et al. (2003b)

    Competitive intensity Number of retailers offering an identical

    product and with service quality ratings

    available from Bizrate.

    Bizrate.com Pan et al. (2003b)

    Price level Average posted price for a product. Bizrate.com Cohen and Areni (1991), Pan et al. (2003b)

    Variance in service quality Coefficient of variation of the service qualityamong retailers Selling a product

    Bizrate.com

    Proportion of National

    Brick-n-Click relations

    Number of National Brick-n-Click retailers

    selling a product.

    Inspection of Retailer

    Websites

    retailer website based on the number of unique visitors. The

    retailers transaction channels were coded based on inspec-

    tion of retailer websites cross-verified with their description

    at Bizrate.com and web21.com5 (Tangand Xing 2002).Using

    location and geographical spread of physical store(s) the

    retailers were classified as:

    National Brick-n-Click: Presence of physical stores inmore than one state.6 (Example: Best Buy with presence

    BestBuy.com)

    Local Brick-n-Click: physical store locations within one

    state. (Example: 17th Street Photo from New York with

    online presence as 17photo.com)

    Pure-Play: no physical stores present. (Example: buy.com

    and amazon.com)

    Catalog provider: if mail-order catalog services are

    offered. (Example: Sears)

    Bias reduction

    We collected 22,209 price quotes, for 1,880 products

    from 233 retailers. For our analyses we only used prices

    quoted for items identified as new by retailers other than

    refurb/discounters. We excluded retailers with missing ser-

    vice quality ratings.7 Though most retailers provide the price

    5 web21.com provides a comprehensive directory listing of retailers and

    their physical store locations (if any).6 In rare cases where the website had insufficient information, the retailer

    was directly contact for the information.7 Bizrate requires a minimum of 30customersurveys over last ninetydays

    to publish ratings information. The exclusion of retailers without service

    Table 3

    Bias reduction reduces analyzable data

    Product

    category

    # Posted-prices # Retailers # Products

    Collected Analyzed Collected Analyzed

    Books 5750 2752 19 9 685

    Camcorder 1386 882 86 57 57

    DVD 9242 5738 30 15 799DVD Player 547 446 66 51 40

    PDA 568 479 77 57 32

    Printer 1087 906 75 54 36

    Scanner 708 574 77 53 31

    Video games 2921 1616 74 42 200

    search engines with product informationsuchasnew, refur-

    bished, the retailers primarily offering refurbished items tend

    not to do so. Refurbished and used products are generally

    sold at lower prices since they differ from new products in

    terms of product quality; thereby leading to a bias in the price

    dispersion measure. We conducted a manual verification of

    each retailers website to identify refurb/discounters,8

    andremoved them from our analyses. Table 3 shows the impact

    of the bias reduction on the size of the final data set, yielding

    a total of 13,393 price points suitable for analysis. To assess

    the qualitative impact of the bias reduction process we exam-

    ratings is methodologically necessary because service rating is a critical

    independent variable in our analysis.8 The classification of refurb/discount retailers was also independently

    verified. Note that the presence of refurbishers can be a significant source of

    bias in the price information. It can certainly increase price dispersion since

    refurbishers are expected to price lower. Yet, to the best of our knowledge,

    no prior study has explicitly accounted for their presence in the data.

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    7/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 315

    ined the dispersion of prices in the collected data and the

    analyzed data and found no significant difference. Although

    no significant difference was observed between the data, we

    believe that the bias reduction provides for more reliable and

    credible parameter estimates in our analyses.

    Calculation of price index

    To account for differences in price levels across different

    products within a category, we index the price charged by a

    retailer for a product.9 The price index is calculated as the

    ratio of the difference between the price charged by a retailer

    and the minimum price for the product to the minimum price

    for the product (Eq. (1)):

    PINDi,j=PINDi,jMinPricej

    MinPricej(1)

    where, PINDi,j = Price index for retailer i for product mar-

    ket j; MinPricej = Minimum price charged by any retailer forproduct market j.

    Measuring service quality

    Bizrate.com provides consumers with fourteen measures

    for service quality of a retailer. These are single-item mea-

    sures on a scale of 1 to 10, where 1 is very poor and 10

    is outstanding. Ten of these items measure the level of ser-

    vice quality of a retailer and includeEase of Finding a

    Product, Product Selection, Clarity of Product Information,

    Look and Design of the website, Shipping Options, Charges

    Stated Clearly, Product Availability,OrderTracking, On-time

    Delivery, and Customer Support. We exclude four items that

    measure the intentions of theshopper to revisit the website, an

    overall rating of the retailer, whether the product met expec-

    tations, and shipping charges, since these four items do not

    directly measure the service quality of a retailer. The service

    quality measure for a retailer i (Servindi) was computed as

    the average of the ten items from Bizrate.com. Such a simple

    composite measure of individual items that measure differ-

    ent aspects of a construct has been widely used for measuring

    the market orientation of an organization (Jaworski and Kohli

    1993), and the service orientation of a retailer (Homburg et

    al. 2002).

    We conducted a principal component factor analysis withthe ten items and found that all the ten items loaded into

    one factor that explained approximately ninety percent of the

    9 We do not include shipping and handling as part of the prices charged

    by the retailer for three reasons: (1) for the product categories used in our

    study, shipping and handling represents only 2 percent of the total price, and

    the correlation between the prices charged by a retailer with and without the

    charges is greater than 0.98 for all the product categories, (2) each retailer

    charges differently for different shipping options and thereby making direct

    comparison difficult, additionally the default shipping options provided in

    Bizrate.com vary from retailer to retailer, and (3) approximately 20 percent

    of the retailers do not report shipping and handling charges on Bizrate.com. Table4

    Descriptivestatistics

    *

    Productcategoryconstruct

    Camcorder

    DVD

    player

    PDA

    Printer

    Sc

    anner

    Books

    DVD

    Videogame

    Pricelevel

    0.2

    3(0.2

    1)

    0.2

    7(0.2

    5)

    0.2

    0(0.2

    0)

    0.2

    2(0.1

    8)

    0

    .25(0.2

    4)

    0.2

    5(0.2

    7)

    0.2

    2(0.

    25)

    0.5

    0(0.9

    6)

    Servicequality

    7.8

    (1.4

    0)

    8.1

    (0.9

    0)

    8.3

    (0.6

    9)

    8.3

    (0.7

    4)

    8

    .3(0.6

    7)

    8.2

    (0.9

    4)

    8.4

    (0.7

    5)

    8.2

    (0.7

    1)

    Size

    **

    277(465)

    334(531)

    108(315)

    139(340)

    154

    (379)

    24(148)

    44(106)

    19(45)

    Pricelevel

    963(671)

    290(242)

    354(170)

    262(154)

    340

    (462)

    15(11)

    30(30)

    32(11)

    Numberofretailers

    15(9.8

    )

    11(7.6

    )

    15(9.2

    )

    25(9.3

    )

    1

    9(7.9

    )

    4(0.9

    )

    7(1.4

    )

    8(4.5

    )

    Variationinservicequality

    0.2

    6(0.2

    2)

    0.1

    1(0.0

    5)

    0.1

    2(0.0

    3)

    0.1

    0(0.0

    2)

    0

    .13(0.0

    6)

    0.1

    9(0.0

    3)

    0.2

    0(0.

    10)

    0.1

    0(0.0

    5)

    Retailertype

    National

    4

    2

    4

    4

    4

    1

    3

    21

    Local

    10

    12

    7

    8

    7

    2

    2

    4

    Click

    43

    37

    46

    42

    42

    6

    10

    17

    Total

    57

    51

    57

    54

    53

    9

    15

    42

    *Valuesinparenthesesrepresentstandardde

    viation;

    **valuesarein1,0

    00s,andrepresenttherankofaretailer.Soalowerrankimpliesalargerretailer.

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    8/16

    316 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Fig. 2. Data structure used for the Hierarchical Linear Model.

    variance.10 We also observed very high correlation between

    the service quality obtained from the factor analysis and the

    measure obtained as the average of the ten individual items.

    The substantive inferences of the study did not change with

    either of the service quality measure. To maintain parsimony

    in our model, we thus use one measure for service quality of

    the retailer as the average of the ten items.

    Market description

    Thedescriptive statistics for the variables used in our anal-

    yses are provided in Table 4. From Table 4 we note that(1)

    the mean of number of retailersin individual product-markets

    is lesser for Books, DVDs, and Videos Games as compared to

    other product categories. While the number of retailers offer-

    ing books, DVDs, and video games is lower, these retailers

    are on average substantially larger than the retailers in other

    product categories, (2) the price dispersion varies from 18

    percent (for printers) to 96 percent (for video games). These

    price dispersion levels are comparable to those reported by

    Pan et al. (2002).

    Hierarchical linear model framework

    Fig. 2 illustrates the structure of the data used in this

    study. As represented in Fig. 2, the variables used to test

    our hypotheses correspond to different levels of aggregation.

    Specifically, retailer characteristics, that is the main effects,

    are at the lowest level of aggregation and are measured for

    each retailer. The market characteristics, that is the moder-

    ating effects, are at a higher level of aggregation and are

    measured for each product market. Such data are designated

    as multilevel data (Raudenbush and Bryk 2002).

    The above data structure suggests that a Hierarchical Lin-ear Modeling (Raudenbush and Bryk 2002; Steenkamp et al.

    1999) framework should naturally accommodate our concep-

    tual model. In HLM, a linear regression model is specified

    at the lowest level of aggregation (Level 1). The intercept

    and slope coefficients for the model at Level 1 are modeled

    as a function of the variables at the next level of aggrega-

    tion (Level 2). We are interested in explaining variation in

    10 Thecronbach alpha measure of scale reliabilityfor theten itemswas also

    found to be 0.92 which is widely acknowledged as an acceptable reliability

    coefficient (Nunnaly 1978).

    prices charged by different retailers for a particular prod-

    uct. The prices charged by the retailer are a function of(a)

    the characteristics of each retailer such as service quality,

    the channels of transaction that are available to the retailer,

    and the size of the retailer, (b) the characteristics of each

    product-market such as number of competitors, average price

    levels and nature of competition, and (c) the interactions of

    the retailer and the market characteristics. The retailer prices

    and characteristics that we are interested in are at the lowest

    level of aggregation and hence form the basis for the Level 1

    regression model. The intercept and slope coefficients of the

    Level 1 model (the retailer level) are modeled as a function

    of the Level 2 variables (market characteristics).

    Proposed HLM model

    In the Level 1 model, the price index of a retailer is influ-

    enced by the various hypothesized retailer characteristics and

    is given by;

    PINDij= 0j+ ij SQi + 2jNBCi + 3

    LBCi

    +4Ci+5

    Sizei+rij (2)

    where SQi = service quality of retailer I; NBCi = 1 if retailer

    i is National Brick-n-Click, 0 otherwise; LBCi = 1 if retailer

    i is Local Brick-n-Click, 0 otherwise; Ci = 1 if online retailer

    i provides a mail-order catalog, 0 otherwise.

    In the Level 1 model, the intercept term (0j), the slope

    coefficients of service quality (1j), and the slope coeffi-

    cient for the indicator of National Brick-n-Click retailer (2j)

    vary across product markets. The Level 2 models explain the

    variation across product markets in the intercept and slope

    coefficients of the Level 1 model. The intercept term is mod-

    eled as,

    0j = 00 + 01 LCMj+ 02 VSQj+ 03

    PLj+ 04 PNBCj+ u0j (3)

    where LCMj = Log of Number of competitors in product-

    market j, PLj = Price level of product-market j, and

    VSQj = Variance in the service quality among the retailers

    in product-market j.

    The slope of service index is modeled as;

    1j= 10 + 11 LCMj+ 12 VSQj

    +13 PLj+ u1j (4)

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    9/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 317

    The slope of National Brick-n-Click is modeled as;

    2j= 20 + 21 PNBCj+ u2j (5)

    where, PNBCj = Proportion of National Brick and Click

    retailers in product-market j.

    Substituting (3)(5) in (2) we get,

    PINDij= 00 + 01 LCMj+ 02 VSQj+ 03

    PLj+ 10 SQi + 20 NBCi

    +3 LBCi + 4 Ci + 5 Sizei + 11

    [LCMi SQi]+ 12 [VSQj SQi]

    +13 [PLj SQi]+ 21 [PNBCjNBCi]

    +[u1j SQi + u2jNBCi]+ [u0j]+ rij (6)

    To test the proposed nonlinear relationship between level

    of competition and price premiums, we use a log conversion

    of number of competitors. 00 represents the average pricecharged by the retailers. rij is a homoscedastic error term

    with mean 0 and variance 2r and represents an estimate of

    the unexplained variance at the retailer level. u0j is a ran-

    dom parameter with mean 0 and variance 2uj and measures

    the deviation of product market j from the mean, that is the

    unexplained variance in prices at the product-market level.11

    A Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML)12

    methodology is used to estimate the model parameters (s,

    s, and us) with an iterative algorithm (details on the esti-

    mation are provided by Raudenbush and Bryk 2002). Using

    Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression on multilevel data

    presents statistical problems because(a) the multilevel dataviolates the assumption of independence (or homogeneity)

    of observations required in OLS, (b) it has been shown that

    the resulting estimates are biased, and (c) the estimated stan-

    dard errors of the effects are too small (Raudenbush and Bryk

    2002). These smaller estimatederrorsin fact lead to improved

    R-square values and also increase the significance of the esti-

    mated coefficients. It is important to note that by adopting the

    HLM approach we are not only estimating a more complex

    model, but also raising the requirements on robustness of the

    estimates from our model.

    Analysis of pricing strategies

    In addition to testing the hypotheses, we are also interested

    in evaluating if the interactions between retailer and market

    factors provide a significant improvement in explaining price

    11 One canalso interpretthe random effects parameteruj, as a heteroscedas-

    ticerrorterm in themixed heteroscdastic models used by Wittink(1977) and

    Shankar and Krishnamurthi (1996).12 We also estimated our models using a Restricted Maximum Likelihood

    (REML) method because when either the number of retailers per product

    market or the number of total prices per product category is small, the FIML

    estimates can have smaller standard errors. We did not find any substantive

    differences in the REML and FIML estimates in our data.

    dispersion. We accomplish this objective by estimating three

    benchmark HLM Null models that are explained below.

    HLM Null Model I

    In HLM Null Model I, the price index of a retailer i in

    product-market j (PINDij), is specified as a function of onlyan intercept term that varies across product markets. Using

    Eq. (6) as the basis, HLM Null Model I is given by:

    PINDij= 00 + u0j+ rij. (7)

    HLM Null Model II

    The HLM Null Model II assumes that the price index of

    a retailer is impacted only by the main effects of retailer

    characteristics. Using Eq. (6) as the basis, HLM Null Model

    II is provided by:

    PINDij = 00 + 10 SQi + 20 NBCi + 3 LBCi

    +4 Ci + 5 Sizei + [u1j SQi + u2j

    NBCi]+ [u0j]+ rij. (8)

    HLM Null Model III

    The HLM Null Model III assumes that the main effects

    of both retailer and market characteristics influence the price

    index of a retailer. Even though it considers only the main

    effects of retailer and market characteristics, the HLM Null

    Model III differs from extant models in the literature because

    it accommodates for the retailer and market characteristics at

    different levels of aggregation. Using Eq. (6) as the basis, the

    HLM Null Model III is represented as;

    PINDij = 00 + 01 LCMj+ 02 VSQj+ 03

    PLj+ 04 PNBCj+ 10 SQi + 20

    NBCi + 3 LBCi + 4 Ci + 5 Sizei

    + [u1j SQi + u2jNBCi]+ [u0j]+ rij (9)

    Results and discussion

    Model comparison

    When FIML is used formodelestimation, a likelihood ratio (LR)

    test is appropriate for evaluating the significance of multiple fixed

    effects in the nested HLM models (Raudenbush and Bryk 2002).

    We evaluate the significance of the main effects of retailer factors

    with a LR test that compares HLM Null Models I and II. The signif-

    icance of the main effects of market factors is established by the LR

    test between HLM Null Models II and III. Finally, the significance

    of the interactions between retailer and market factors is obtained

    through a LR test between HLM Null Model III and the Proposed

    HLM Model. We assess the explanatory power of a model by com-

    puting the observed variance in prices (Vp) with the variance of

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    10/16

    318 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Table 5a

    Comparison of reduction in price dispersion

    Camcorder

    (n = 882)

    DVD player

    (n = 547)

    PDA

    (n = 479)

    Printer

    (n = 906)

    Scanner

    (n = 574)

    Books

    (n = 2752)

    DVDs

    (n = 5738)

    Video Games

    (n = 1616)

    Likelihood values

    Proposed HLM Model 503 25 430 525 92 141 2318 2935

    HLM Null Model 3 493 16 424 498 83 134 2270 2925

    HLM Null Model 2 484 13 419 481 72 97 2243 2877HLM Null Model 1 400 4 405 425 60 55 2152 2840

    Likelihood ratio

    Interaction effectsa 19 18 12 54 18 14 96 20

    Main effects-market factorsb 19 6* 10** 34 22 82 54 96

    Main effects-retailer factorsc 167 18 28 112 24 84 182 74

    R-square

    Proposed HLM Model 0.42 0.42 0.56 0.35 0.44 0.67 0.59 0.70

    HLM Null Model 3 0.34 0.35 0.48 0.21 0.37 0.62 0.54 0.62

    HLM Null Model 2 0.34 0.32 0.41 0.18 0.35 0.49 0.41 0.61

    HLM Null Model 1 0.18 0.29 0.33 0.16 0.23 0.40 0.36 0.63

    Simple Linear Model 0.27 0.29 0.05 0.11 0.08 0.34 0.36 0.62

    *Significant at < 0.10, **significant at < 0.05, and all other cells for the likelihood ratio tests are significant at < 0.01.a

    LR test between HLM Full Model and Null Model III.b LR test between HLM Null Models III and II.c LR test between HLM Null Models II and I.

    the residuals from the corresponding model (Vr) for each product

    category. The explanatory power is assessed by an R2 measure cal-

    culated as [1 (Vr/Vp)]. In addition to the HLM Null Models (I, II,

    & III) we also compare the Proposed Model with a Simple Linear

    Model incorporating only retailer characteristics (similar to Pan et

    al. 2002). The variables in Simple Linear Model are service qual-

    ity, channels of transactionNational Brick-n-Click retailer, Local

    Brick-n-Click retailer, existence of mail-order catalog, and size of a

    retailer.13

    The LR test between the Proposed HLM Model and the HLM

    Null Model III is significant at < 0.01 for all the eight productcategories (Table 5a); providing strong support for the influence

    of the interactions between retailer and market factors on retailer

    prices. For six of the eight product categories we find strong sup-

    port ( < 0.01) for the main effects of market factors on retailer

    prices. The main effects of market factors are only marginally sig-

    nificant for the DVD Player (< 0.10) and PDA product categories

    (< 0.05). Finally, for all the eight product categories, the main

    effects of retailer factors have a significant influence on retailer

    prices. We see that the Proposed HLM Model of price dispersion

    provides a higher explanatory than all of the Null Models. Specifi-

    cally, on an average the Proposed Model explains 52 percent of the

    variation in retailer prices. In comparison, on average theHLM Null

    Models I, II, and III approximately explain 32, 39 and 44 percent of

    the variation in retailer prices, respectively. The R2 for the Proposed

    HLM Model ranges from 21 percent (printers) to 70 percent (video

    games).

    Overall, the better fit between the model and the online market

    structure is reflected by average improvement of 25 percent in R2

    over the empirical evidence in existing literature. The suitability of

    HLM structure is also evident in ability of the HLM Null Model 1

    to explain greater degree of price dispersion than the Simple Linear

    Model.

    13 The Simple Linear Model is provided by PINDij =0 +1 SQi +2 NBCi +3 LBCi +4 Ci +5 Size + rij.

    Main effects-influence of retailer characteristics

    Table 5b provides the results from the estimation of the HLM

    model with all covariates (labeled as Proposed HLM Model in

    Table 5a).

    Service quality

    For all the eight product categories the statistically significant

    positive coefficient for service quality indicates that retailers with

    higher service quality are also charging higher prices. Across prod-uct categories we find consistent evidence that retailers consider

    service quality as a means for differentiating and thereby charg-

    ing higher prices (supporting H1). We believe that this consistently

    significant influence of service quality is observed because our

    framework accounts for retailer and market characteristics at two

    different levels, and also incorporates their interactions.

    Channels of transaction

    In our analyses, a retailer is classified as pure play, National

    brick-n-click, Local Brick-n-Click, and catalog. All of the chan-

    nel classifications are used in the analyses with the exception of

    pure play, which is used as the base. The coefficients for each

    of the retailer classifications are thus interpreted as the average

    increase/decrease in the prices relative to a pure play retailer. Over-

    all, we observe that the retailer channel structure has a significant

    influence on the prices charged by retailers.

    Our results support H2a. We find that National Brick-n-Click

    retailers charge significantly higher prices than the pure play retail-

    ers in all of the eight product categories. The increase in price levels

    for National Brick-n-Click retailers ranges from 6 percent (printers)

    to 39 percent (DVD players). If the National Brick-n-Click retailers

    were to become cost leaders and price their products in relation to

    their economies of scale, one would expect to observe lower prices

    and not the higher prices that our results indicate. We believe that

    the National Brick-n-Click retailers are able to charge higher prices

    because(1) they are able to engender trust among online shoppers

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    11/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 319

    Table 5b

    Results from estimation of hierarchical linear model

    Camcorder

    (n = 882)

    DVD

    player

    (n = 547)

    PDA

    (n = 479)

    Printer

    (n = 906)

    Scanner

    (n = 574)

    Books

    (n = 2752)

    DVDs

    (n = 5738)

    Video

    games

    (n = 1616)

    Product-market factors

    Log of number of competitors 0.015 0.60** 0.13** 0.16* 0.03 0.07** 0.40** 1.65***

    Variance in service quality 0.03* 0.03 0.41 0.13 0.36* 0.46* 1.53** 0.43Price level 3.3E-5 5.8E-3 7.9E-6 1.2E-4 8E-6* 2E-3** 0.015*** 0.11

    Proportion-National Brick-n-Click 1.3E-05 1.70*** 0.24 0.58 3.0E-6 0.33*** 0.062 0.50

    Retailer factors

    Service quality 0.01** 0.20** 0.02* 0.04*** 0.08*** 0.008* 0.030*** 0.15***

    National Brick-n-Click 0.16*** 0.39*** 0.09*** 0.06* 0.08* 0.33*** 0.062*** 0.17*

    Local Brick-n-Click 0.02 0.03 0.05*** 0.021 0.02 0.25*** 0.09 0.07

    Catalog 0.10*** 0.12 0.04** 0.048*** 0.02 0.05*** 0.02* 0.08

    Size 33.7*** 34.1*** 5.7* 3.1 2.3 5.8** 2.4*** 1.3**

    Interaction effects

    Price level service quality 8.2E-6 4.2E-5 1E-4 9.2E-4 2.0E-5 2E-3* 1.7E-3*** 0.012

    Log of number of

    competitors service quality

    6.7E-3 0.07*** 0.03* 0.025** 0.02*** 0.03*** 0.041*** 0.22***

    Variance in service

    quality service quality

    0.04*** 0.27*** 0.29*** 1.81** 0.22** 0.07 0.43*** 1.41**

    Proportion of National

    Brick-n-ClickNational

    Brick-n-Click

    1.03** 4.71*** 0.48*** 0.35 0.15 0.13*** 0.59** 0.26*

    *Significant at < 0.10, **significant at < 0.05, ***significant at < 0.01.

    given their national presence and brand recognition, and (2) appro-

    priate use of technology enables these retailers to provide shoppers

    additional convenience in terms of being able to switch channels of

    transaction frompre-ordering to post-fulfillment, for exampleorder-

    ing online and taking delivery offline at a nearby store. Arguably,

    such conveniences are part of a higher level of service quality that

    a retailer offers and the national retailers are clearly able to charge

    a premium for these additional services.14

    These findings provideadditional empirical support to previous findings that multichannel

    retailers charge higher prices than pure-play retailers (Ancarani and

    Shankar 2004).

    The Local Brick-n-Click retailers are observed to be(a) charg-

    ing significantly lower prices (than pure play retailers) in the PDA

    (5 percent lower) product category, (b) significantly higher prices in

    the books product category (25 percent higher), and (c) no signifi-

    cant difference in their price levels for the remaining 6 categories.

    In summary, we find that for a majority of product categories ana-

    lyzed, Local Brick-n-Click retailers are not charging a premium for

    the facilities that their multichannel operation provides. The Local

    Brick-n-Click retailersseem to be using their Internet operations for

    bettergeographic reach,as there areminimal marginalcostsin oper-

    ating an Internet retail store. In this regard, it should also be noted

    that for customers outside of the geographic reach of the physical

    store, the Local Brick-and-Click retailer is equivalent to a pure-play

    retailer because none of the advantages of multichannel transactions

    are available.

    Finally, retailers providing mail-order catalogs in addition to

    their website are found to be charging higher prices for three prod-

    uct categories (camcorder - 10 percent higher, printers and books -

    14 Note that in addition to the price levels all National Brick-and-Click

    retailers also charge the sales taxes in almost all states. Consequently, con-

    sumers are de-factopayinga premiumsignificantlyhigher thanthat indicated

    in our results.

    5 percent higher). However, for two product categories they charge

    lower prices than pure play retailers (PDA - 4 percent lower, and

    DVDs - 2 percent lower). These results indicate that providing an

    additional channel of transaction (such as a catalog) does influence

    retailer pricing strategies, but the effect of providing a catalog in

    addition to a website varies by product category. Therefore, we do

    not find support for H2b. In summary, our results provide conclu-

    sive evidence that National Brick-n-Click retailers charge higherprices than pure-play retailers, while the same is not true for Local

    Brick-n-Click retailers and online retailers with mail-order cata-

    logs. Our results imply that while previous research has classified

    retailers in the online markets as either pure-play or brick-and-click

    (Pan et al. 2002; Tang and Xing 2002), there is finer distinction

    among brick-and-click retailers, with only the national brick-and-

    click retailers consistently charging higher prices than pure-play

    retailers.

    Moderating influence of market characteristics

    Given that the interaction between retailer characteristics and

    market characteristics are significant for a majority of the productcategories, we do not discuss the individual main effects of the

    influence of market characteristics on the pricing strategies of the

    retailers.

    Level of competition and service quality

    In seven of the eight product categories (all product categories

    except camcorders) the coefficient of the interaction between com-

    petitive intensity and service quality is negative and significant,

    hencesupporting H3. The significance of coefficient indicatesthat an

    increase in the level of competition in a product market diminishes

    the positive impact that service quality hason the price charged by a

    retailer. However, the negative influence of level of competition has

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    12/16

    320 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    diminishing returns, indicating a weakening strength of the decrease

    in the price charged with increasing number of competitors.

    Price level and service quality

    We hypothesized that the consumers selection of a retailer is

    based on risk averseness particularly when the price of a product is

    high. This would lead consumersto preferretailers with high service

    quality, who would in turn benefit from the consumers risk averse-

    ness (or willingness to pay higher for service quality) by charging

    higher prices. The results indicate a positive and significant rela-

    tionship between price level and service quality for only Books and

    DVDs. Therefore, for six of the eight product categories we do not

    find support for H4. Similar to Pan et al. (2003b) we do not find a

    strong support for the moderating influence of price levels on the

    relationship between service quality and prices. The weak influence

    of price levels on the premium charged by retailers could be that

    for products with higher price levels, consumers can search online

    for product information with ease. Once the consumers decide on a

    product to purchase, they make a choice of the retailer based on the

    various characteristics of the retailers offering the product. There-

    fore, we are unlikely to observe a moderating influence of pricelevels in our analyses.

    Nature of competition: variance in service quality and service

    quality

    We find significant support for a positive interaction effect

    between variance in service quality of retailers selling the prod-

    uct and the service quality of a retailer (H5a) for seven product

    categories (all product categories except books). The retailers

    who provide a high level of service quality further increase the

    price levels with increase in scope for service differentiation,

    which is typically marked by presence of low quality retailers.

    In such product-markets with high variation in service qual-

    ity it is easier for high service quality retailers to justify their

    premiums.

    Nature of competition: proportion of national retailers and

    national retailer

    For six of the eight product categories (camcorders, DVD play-

    ers, PDA, Books, DVDs, and Video Games), national retailers

    reduce their prices as the proportion of national retailers in the

    product-market increases (H5b). Our results show that while the

    national retailers charge higher prices than others, they do so

    only as long as competition from other national retailers in the

    product-market is low. An increase in the number of national

    retailers in the product-market diminishes the scope for ser-

    vice differentiation for national retailers in terms of multichannel

    characteristics, thereby exerting a downward pressure on theirprices.

    Total effect of service quality

    An important objective of our study is to evaluate the effect

    of service quality of a retailer on prices charged. We propose that

    after accounting for market characteristics service quality would

    have a positive influence on the prices charged. In order to make

    inferences regarding the influence of service quality we investi-

    gate the total impact of service quality that includes both the main

    and the moderating effects. Evaluation of the total effects is par-

    ticularly important because the moderating influences of market

    characteristics are found to have opposing forces - level of com-

    petition is observed to negatively impact the relationship, whereas

    the nature of competition is found to positively impact the rela-

    tionship between retailers service quality and prices charged. The

    total effects of service quality measures the impact of a change in

    service quality of a retailer on the prices charged, and is obtained

    by taking the first derivative of Eq. (6) with respect to service

    quality;15

    PIND

    ServQi= 10 + 11 [Log(#of competitors)i]+ 12

    [VServindj]+ [u1j] (11)

    Foreach product category, we plotted thevalues of thederivative

    given by (11) for all the observations, that is for all the observed

    values of level of competition and the nature of competition. The

    plots indicate that the sign of the derivative is positive across the

    range of the data used in our study. We can safely conclude that for

    all product categories, and over a wide range of values of level of

    competition and nature of competition, service quality has a positiveinfluence of the prices charged. The change in the derivative, over

    the various values of level and nature of competition are shown in

    Fig. 3 for two representative product categoriesPDAs and DVD

    Players.

    Fig. 3 shows that for both DVD Players and PDAs, the prices

    charged by a retailer increases with the variation in service quality

    (nature of competition) and decreases at a diminishing rate with the

    number of retailers (level of competition. Specifically, we observe

    that as the number of retailers offering a product increases beyond

    11 for DVD Players, and 20 for PDAs,the diminishing impact of the

    level of competition on prices charged is minimized. Overall, the

    change in prices charged by the retailer over the range of values for

    level and nature of competition is positive for an increase in service

    quality.

    Independent analyses of pure-play and brick-and-click retailers

    It can be argued that brick-and-click retailers have a larger set

    of constraints, such as price consistency between the offline stores

    and Internet stores that would impact their pricing strategies. These

    factors are not accounted for in our analyses and can potentially

    confound the observed results. To eliminate any possibility of such

    confounding effects, we separately estimated the model coefficients

    using only the pure-play retailers and only brick-and-click retailers

    (both national and local). The results of our analyses areprovided in

    Appendix A. TableA1 shows thatthe results fromthe separateanaly-

    ses aresimilarto theresults obtained by pooling both pure-playonlyand brick-and-click retailers. We conducted a pooling test (Kumar

    and Leone 1988) to examine whether data for pure-play retailers

    and brick-n-click retailers can be combined. We could not reject the

    null hypothesis that the pooling is appropriate (for = 0.01). We

    find that the coefficients of pure-play only retailers are similar to

    the brick-n-click retailers, which implies that the factors outlined

    in our study impact the pricing decisions of retailers irrespective of

    their channel structure.

    15 For Books and DVD players we find a significant positive influence of

    pricelevels, which is alsoincluded in equation10 forcalculating total effects.

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    13/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 321

    Fig. 3. Total effects of service quality on online prices.

    Implications, limitations and future research

    Theoretical implications

    The results from this study contribute significantly to the

    current understanding of the sources of price differentiation

    by online retailers. Our study extends previous findings on

    how retailer characteristics such as service quality and chan-

    nels of transaction (Pan et al. 2002; Ancarani and Shankar

    2004) impact the prices. We also show how market char-

    acteristics such as number of competitors influence price

    dispersion in online markets. In particular,our proposed com-prehensive model explains greater amount of variance in

    prices and provides empirical evidence that retailer and mar-

    ket characteristics interact to determine the prices charged by

    a retailer. Our key findings include: (1) a positive influence of

    service quality on prices across severalproduct categories; (2)

    similar to prior findings (Pan et al. 2002), an increase in num-

    ber of competitors induces a downward pressure in prices for

    all retailers, albeit at a decreasing rate; (3) for the first time in

    the literature, we show how the increase in scope for service

    differentiation is leveraged by high service quality retailers to

    increase their prices particularly in face of high competition;

    (4) interestingly we find that low service quality retailers in

    fact seek higher prices in markets characterized by either a

    large numberof competitors andlow variation in service qual-

    ity or in markets with a large variance in service quality and

    few competitors, and (5) National Brick-and-Click retailers

    reducetheirpricesinfaceofincreasingcompetitioninformof

    other National Brick-and-Click retailers. The findings from

    our study pertain to retailer characteristics, market charac-

    teristics and their interactive effects, thereby highlighting the

    importance of incorporating the hierarchical structure of the

    market in a unified empirical model when studying pricing

    strategies of online retailers.

    Managerial implications

    We expect that in a wide variety of product-markets our

    findings will serve as benchmarks for retailers choices of

    service quality and channels of transaction. Such bench-

    marks are especially useful for established retailers who are

    in the midst of adding new products to their portfolio, and

    for new entrants jointly deciding market entry, service qual-

    ity and channel related investments and prices. To provide

    an illustration of such a benchmark analysis, we conducted

    a post-hoc analysis with comparison of price levels across

    eight product-market segments.

    Table 6

    Comparison of premiums over segments

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    14/16

    322 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Table A1

    Results from estimation of Hierarchical Linear Model

    Camcorder DVD player PDA Printer Scanner Books DVDs Video games

    Pure-play

    Product-market factors

    Log (number of competitors) 0.012 0.43*** 0.18*** 0.14*** 0.07*** 0.10 0.24* 1.03***

    Variance in service quality 0.001 0.05*** 0.57** 0.29 0.49 0.35* 1.21** 0.41

    Price level 4.5E-6 5.4E-3 1.8E-6 3.2E-4 4.1E-6 6E-6* 0.007** 8.0E-2**

    Retailer factors

    Service quality 0.07** 0.018** 0.015* 0.19*** 0.14** 0.006*** 0.09* 0.23*

    Size 31.4** 35.1*** 2.6* 3.8 3.2 4.2 2.2*** 1.9***

    Interaction effects

    Price level service quality 4.8E-6 5.5E-5 2.0E-4 1.0E-5 7.2E-6 1E-4 2E-4** 0.008

    Log (number of

    competitors) service quality

    5.1E-3 0.04*** 0.03** 0.06*** 0.04*** 0.01*** 0.015* 0.11**

    Variance in service

    quality service quality

    0.05* 0.34*** 0.31*** 0.04* 0.13** 0.01 0.09* 1.11**

    Brick-n-Click only

    Product-market factors

    Log (number of competitors) 0.14 0.96*** 0.04** 0.02** 0.14 0.18 0.02*** 0.06

    Variance in service quality 0.009 0.02 0.29 0.59 0.24 0.02 1.9 0.62

    Price level 2.2E-5* 4.5E-4 2.8E-6 3.1E-4 5E-6 5.7E-3 0.005 9.2E-3**

    Retailer factors

    Service Quality 0.05 0.31*** 0.07* 0.01*** 0.08** 0.01** 0.08*** 0.10**

    Size 37.0 36.1*** 6.7*** 2.7 2.1 6.1*** 1.2*** 1.1

    Interaction effects

    Price level service quality 7.1E-6 3.7E-5 9E-5 3.7E-5 2.2E-5 1.3E-3 8.5E-3 3.6E-3

    Log (number of competitors)

    service quality

    7E-3 0.10*** 0.028 0.009* 0.01*** 0.06* 0.058** 0.28**

    Variance in service quality

    service quality

    0.03* 0.21** 0.28*** 0.03 0.01 0.009 0.32** 1.96**

    *Significant at < 0.10, **significant at < 0.05, ***significant at < 0.01.

    We performed a median split of service quality, level ofcompetition and variance in service quality to obtain two lev-

    els (High and Low) for each of the three factors resulting in

    eight segments. We then compared the mean price premi-

    ums charged by retailers across these segments. The results

    of this comparison (based on a MANOVA) are provided in

    Table 6.

    From Table 6 we obtain the following insights on how the

    premium of a retailer with a certain level of service quality

    (high, low) varies across market conditions (level and nature

    of competition).

    1. Low service quality retailer charges lowest premium in

    markets with low competition and little scope for service

    differentiation (cell 4). Any change in intensity of compe-

    tition and/or availability for service differentiation (cells

    1, 2, and 3), yield increased premiums for the retailer.

    It needs to be emphasized that though the premiums

    increase, they are not different from each other, that is

    level of premium is not significantly different across cells

    1, 2, and 3.

    2. In contrast, a high service quality retailer charges high-

    est premium in markets characterized by low competition

    and low scope for differentiation (cell 8). Additionally,

    the high service quality retailer is able to seek similar

    high premiums in highly competitive markets with a highpotential for service differentiation (cell 5).

    We obtain the following insights on how the premiums

    charged between the high and low service quality retailers

    varies within same market conditions,

    1. High service quality retailer charges significantly higher

    than the low service quality retailer when(a) level

    of competition and scope for differentiation are high

    (cell 5 vs. cell 1), and (b) both level of competition

    and scope for service differentiation are low (cell 8 vs.

    cell4).

    2. Most importantly, under no market condition is the lowservice quality retailer able to charge significantly higher

    premium than the higher service quality retailers.

    The above analyses, clearly identifies the market condi-

    tions that aresuitable for retailers with a given level of service

    quality and transaction channels for charging higher prices.

    Such an analysis maps out the decision space for retailers,

    giving them quantifiable measures of tradeoffs that are crit-

    ical for making informed entry in a product market, pricing

    decisions and investment levels for strategic positioning in

    terms of service quality. Finally, we note that these insights

    arebasedon post-hoc analyses of theresults from ourconcep-

  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    15/16

    R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309 324 323

    tual model and serve as guidelines for detailed examination

    by future research.

    Limitations and future research

    Current price dispersion research, which includes this

    study, is limited by not having access to supply side costdata. Future research needs to address revenue measures that

    consider the actual transacted prices. It is possible for the

    dispersion of transacted prices are made is different from

    the dispersion in retailer prices. Further, we believe that fac-

    tors such as product life cycle and timing of market entry

    need to be analyzed (Pan et al. 2002, 2003b), implying the

    necessity of longitudinal data. Note that pricing is one of the

    many strategic decision criteria that a retailer has to manage

    in order to optimize profits. For instance, Internet retailers

    are also interested in building a market share, and in ensur-

    ing consumer retention. Future studies should compare the

    influence of service quality across these different decisioncriteria and investigate the process through which they lead

    to optimal profits for retailers. Our results indicate channel

    choice affects the pricing strategy of the online retailer. In

    fact we find that retailers providing multiple channels of

    transaction also charge higher prices. Future research should

    investigate whether providing multiple channels of transac-

    tion also increases the revenues of the retailers, and why

    providing multiple channels of transaction affects consumer

    choice and willingness to pay. Given that price dispersion

    as a metric intrinsically signals the confluence of consumer

    search, retailer pricing strategies and informational efficiency

    of markets, we hope that our integrated approach will be use-

    ful to other researchers examining the interactions between

    these competing forces in electronic markets.

    Acknowledgements

    The authors thank V. Kumar, Jim Marsden, and Alok

    Gupta for their helpful comments.

    Appendix A. Separate Analysis of Pure-Play and

    Brick-And-Click Retailers

    (See Table A1).

    References

    Ancarani, Fabio and Venkatesh Shankar (2004). Price levels and price

    dispersion within and across multiple retailer types: Further evidence

    and extension, Journal of Academy of Marketing Science, 32 (2) 176

    187.

    Ba,Sulin andPaul A. Pavlou (2002). Evidenceof theeffect of trust building

    technology in electronic markets: Price premiums and buyer behavior,

    MIS Quarterly, 26 (3) 269289.

    Barney, Jay (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage,

    Journal of Management, 17 99120.

    Baye, Michael R. and JohnMorgan (2001). Information gatekeepers on the

    Internet and the competitiveness of homogeneous product markets, The

    American Economic Review, 91 (3) 454474.

    Baye, Michael R. and John Morgan (2003). Red Queen Pricing Effects in

    E-Retail Markets, http://ssrn.com.

    Baylis, Kathy and Jeffrey M. Perloff (2002). Price dispersion on the Inter-

    net: Good firms and bad firms, Review of Industry Organization, 21

    305324.

    Betancourt, Roger andDavid Gautschi(1993).Demandcomplementarities,

    household production, and retail assortments, Marketing Science, 9 (2)

    146161.

    Carlton, Dennis W. and Judith A. Chevalier (2001). Free Riding and Sales

    Strategies for the Internet, NBER Working Paper # 8067.

    Chen, Pei-yu and Lorin M. Hitt (2003). Understanding Price Dispersion

    in Internet-Enabled Markets, Working Paper, The Wharton School of

    Business, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104.

    Chintagunta, Pradeep (2002). Investigating category pricing behavior at a

    retail chain, Journal of Marketing Research, 39 (2) 141154.

    Clay, Karen, Ramayya Krishnan and E. Wolff (2001). Prices and price

    dispersion on the web: Evidence from the online bookindustry,Journal

    of Industrial Economics, 49 (4) 521539.

    ClayS Karen, RamayyaKrishnan, E. Wolffand D. Fernandes(2002).Retail

    strategies on the web:Price and non-pricecompetitionin the online book

    industry, Journal of Industrial Economics, 50 (3) 351367.

    Cohen, Joel B. and Charles S. Areni (1991). Affect and consumer behav-

    ior, in Handbook of Consumer Behavior, T. S. Robertson and H. H.

    Kassarjian eds. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall., 188240.

    Cohen, Marcel (2000a). The impact of brandselection on pricecompetition

    - A double-edged sword, Applied Economics, 32 (5) 601609.

    Cohen, Marcel (2000b). Consumer involvement - driving up the cost,

    Consumer Policy Review, 10 (4) 122125.

    Doolin, Bill, Laurie McLeod, Bob McQueen and Mark Watton (2003).

    Internetstrategies forestablished retailers:Four NewZealandcase stud-

    ies, Journal of Information Technology Cases and Applications, 4 (5)

    320.

    eMarketer (Aug., 2004). Online Selling and CRM, eMarketer.Homburg,Christian, WayneD. Hoyer andMartinFassnacht (2002). Service

    orientation of a retailers businessstrategy:Dimensions,antecedents, and

    performance outcomes, Journal of Marketing, 66 (4) 86101.

    Jaworski, Bernard J. and Ajay K. Kohli (1993). Market orientation:

    Antecedents and consequences, Journal of Marketing, 57 (3) 5370.

    Kirmani, Amna and Akshay R. Rao (2000). No pain, no gain: A criti-

    cal review of the literature on signaling unobservable product quality,

    Journal of Marketing, 64 (2) 6679.

    Kumar, V. and Robert P. Leone (May, 1988). Measuring the effect of retail

    store promotions on brand and store substitution, Journal of Marketing

    Research, 25 178185.

    Lal, Rajiv andMikolasSarvary(1999). Whenand how is theInternetlikely

    to decrease price competition, Marketing Science, 18 (4) 485503.

    Mullaney, TimothyJ. (Feb. 17, 2003). TheWeb is Finally CatchingProfits,

    in BusinessWeek.Nunnaly, J. (1978). Psychometric Theory, New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Pakes, Ariel (2003). A reconsideration of hedonic price indexes with

    an application to PCs, American Economic Review, 93 (5) 1578

    1596.

    Pan,Xing, BrianT.Ratchfordand VenkateshShankar (2002).Can pricedis-

    persion in online markets be explained by differences in E-Tailer service

    quality, Journal of Academy of Marketing Science, 30 (4) 433445.

    Pan, Xing, Brian T. Ratchford and Venkatesh Shankar (2003). The evolu-

    tion of price dispersion in Internet retail markets, Advances in Applied

    Microeconomics: Organizing the New Industrial Economy, 12 85105.

    Pan, Xing, Brian T. Ratchford and Venkatesh Shankar (July, 2003b). Why

    Arent the Prices of the Same Item the Same at Me.com and You.com?:

    Drivers of Price Dispersion Among E-Tailers, Working Paper, Univer-

    sity of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742.

    http://ssrn.com/http://ssrn.com/
  • 7/28/2019 mohan mba imsr

    16/16

    324 R. Venkatesan et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (3, 2007) 309324

    Pan, Xing, Brian T. Ratchford and Venkatesh Shankar (2004). Price dis-

    persion on the Internet: A review and directions for future research,

    Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18 (4) 116135.

    Porter, Michael (2001). Strategy and the Internet, Harvard Business

    Review, 79 6378.

    Pratt, John, David Wise and Richard Zeckhauser (May, 1979). Price differ-

    ences in almost competitive markets, Quarterly Journal of Economics,

    93 189211.

    Quick, Rebecca (Nov. 30, 2000). New Page in E-Retailing: Catalogs

    Forget Gee-Whiz Technology; Web Stores Say Snail Mail is Cool Tool

    of the Future, Wall S treet Journal, B1.

    Ratchford, Brian T., Xing Pan and Venkatesh Shankar (2003). On the effi-

    ciency of Internet markets for consumergoods,Journal of Public Policy

    and Marketing, 22 (1) 416.

    Raudenbush, Stephen and Anthony S. Bryk (2002). Hierarchical Linear

    Models: Applications and Data Ana lysis Methods, Thousand Oaks: CA:

    Sage Publications, Inc.

    Shankar, Venkatesh and Ruth Bolton (2004). An empirical analysis of

    determinants of retailer pricing strategies, Marketing Science, 23 (1)

    2849.

    Shankar, Venkatesh and Lakshman Krishnamurthi (1996). Relating price

    sensitivityto retailer promotionalvariables andpricingpolicy:An empir-

    ical analysis, Journal of Retailing, 72 (3) 249272.

    Smith, Michael (2001). The Law of One Price? The Impact of IT-Enabled

    Markets on Consumer Search and Retailer Pricing, Working Paper,

    Carnegie Mellon University.

    Steenkamp, Jan-Benedict E.M., Frenkel ter Hofstede and Michel Wedel

    (April, 1999). A cross-national investigation into the individual and

    national cultural antecedents of consumer innovativeness, Journal of

    Marketing, 63 5569.

    Tang,Fang-Fang and Xialon Xing(2001). Will the growth of multi-channel

    retailing diminish the pricing efficiency of the web?, Journal of Retail-

    ing, 77 319333.

    Varian, Hal R. (2000). Market structure in the network age, in Under-

    standing the Digital Economy, Erik. Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin eds.

    Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Wittink, Dick R. (May, 1977). Exploring territorial differences in the rela-

    tionship between marketing variables, Journal of Marketing Research,

    25 145155.

    Wolfinbarger, Mary and May C. Gilly (2003). e-TailQ: Dimensionalizing,

    measuring, and predicting eTail quality, Journal of Retailing, 79 (3)

    183198.

    Zeithaml, Valarie, A. Parasuraman and Arvind Malhotra (2002). Service

    quality delivery through web sites, Journal of Academy of Marketing

    Science, 30 (4) 275362.